The structure of the Malaysian poultry industry is different from the one that existed in the nineties, due largely to vertical coordination and integration. Independent and self-operated activities that once dominated the production system have been replaced by contracts and outright ownership and operation of the production by integrators. By this many individual poultry processing companies own almost all aspects of production-breeding farms, multiplication farms, hatcheries, feed mills, some broiler growing farms, and processing plants. The structure therefore, involve an aspect of integrated production-marketing systems which involves a single firm owning and operating every aspect of production from importing parent stock to marketing packaged chicken-meats in company owned outlets. For instance the ex-farm level has been dominated by the integrators because there are only four (4) companies controlling 100% share of the importation of the breeder birds. The four integrated companies are Ayamas breeder Farm Sdn Bhd, CAB breeding Farm Sdn Bhd, Charoen Pokphand Farm sdn Bhd and Leong Hup Poultry Farm Sdn Bhd. There are ninety two (92) Parent stock (multiplication) farms owned by twenty five (25) separate companies. According to DVS (2012) report ten (10) of these multiplication companies are owned and operated by integrators. There are fifty three (53) hatcheries in Peninsular Malaysia, thirty one or more than 58% of the hatcheries owned and operated by integrators. The total day-old chicks (DOC) production in 2011 by the industry was estimated at 653, 006, 812 million chicks, and the integrators contributed 70. 75% of the total (DVS, 2011). The Department of Statistics (DOS) Malaysia report on the census of agricultural establishments shows there are only 292 poultry farming establishments registered in Malaysia as against more than 3, 500 reported by DVS suggesting that integrators are likely to owned and operate multiple farms and that a number of independent operated farms are not formally registered. Report from DVS, (2011) have shown that Malaysian broiler-chicken industry control 62. 56% of the total chicken meat supply in the Peninsular Malaysia and non-integrators control 21. 4% share of the supply.
Problem statement
Although the integrating production system allows the firm to achieve economies of scale, decrease transactions costs, as well as the ability to closely monitor product quality at every stage of production by controlling all inputs and processes at every level. However, on the other hand the traditional structure-conduct-performance paradigm hypothesized that the level of concentration in a particular market will influence the degree of competition among firms in that market. Markets that are highly concentrated (few large firms dominating the market) are less competitive than markets where concentration is low. As such, according to the hypothesis, firms in less competitive environment charge higher prices and reap monopolistic profits. A higher price above marginal cost implies inefficient allocation of resources and the resulting implication is production inefficiency. A concentrated industry structure could therefore weaken the efficiency and effectiveness of market performance. In view of this, the study is aimed to evaluate the indicators of competition in the supply chain of the Malaysian poultry industry.
Objective of the Study
In broad sense the objective of the study is to evaluate the indicators of competitiveness of the Malaysian poultry industry supply chain; specifically
To assess the structure, conduct and market performance of the Malaysian poultry supply chain
To determine the strategic behaviours of the firms and relationship among supply chain participants of the industry.
To describe the farm-retail-wholesale price spread along the supply chain to observe symmetry or otherwise in the price transmission process within the industry as an indicator of price setter and taker
Theoretical Framework and Methodology
The concept of S-C-P which emanated from industrial organization studies primarily to analyze the competitive conditions in industries by examining how the industry structure relates to market conduct and its performance was explored in this study. The S-C-P framework postulates that as market structure deviates from the ideal perfect competition, the extent of competitiveness of the market will decrease and consequently a decline in market efficiency (Scarborough and Kydd, 1992).
The S-C-P Model
Concentration Ratio classification
Market structure CR4 CR8
Highly concentrated 75-100
Moderately concentrated 50-75 slightly concentrated 25-50 Atomistic 0-25 <33
HHI
HHI < 1000= concentrated market
1000 HHI> 1800= highly concentrated (Joe Bain’s classification) Market Structure Indicators Concentration Ratio Herfindahl-Hirschman Index Gini Coefficient Lorenz Curve Advertising Intensity Capital Intensity Return on Assets Return on Shareholders’ Equity Return on Sales The study also incorporated the concept of co-integration to examine the relationship between prices i. e. farm-wholesale-retail in the price transmission mechanism. Von Cramon-Taubadel and Fahlbusch (1994) were among the first to incorporate the concept of co-integration into models of asymmetric price transmission. They extended a standard error correction model (ECM) by incorporating of asymmetric adjustments terms. The procedure involves estimating a relationship between prices (e. g retail and farm-level) using simple ordinary least square (OLS). If the prices can be referred to as co-integrated, the estimated coefficient of the OLS is an estimate of the long-term equilibrium relationship between the two variables. The inclusion of the ECT allows the estimated price to respond to the changes in the explanatory variables but also correct any deviation from the long-run equilibrium that may be left over from the previous periods. The ECT model takes the following form; Δ= + + + + Z*EC1t-1 + ___________________________ (1) = + + + β3ΔPwt-I + Z*EC2t-I + _____________________ (2) Where, αi and βi are short-run coefficients and EC1 and EC2 are error correction terms, and are residuals in the equation (1) and (2) respectively. The analysis of the results shows that there are 561, 567, and 447 firms operating in the entire industry in 2009, 2010, and 2011 respectively. The firms were categorized into six industries based on five digit code of the MSIC, 2008. The six industries were further grouped based on type of business of the firm into ex-farm, wholesale and retail market supply chain. The results revealed there has been increase in the total revenue in the entire industry from RM12. 2b in 2009 to RM13. 6b in 2011. The average CR4 and CR8 of the ex-farm market level have slightly increase from 2009 to 2011 but remain within the quartile of moderately concentrated. The wholesale segment witnessed the same trend with CR4 31. 9 and 40. 6% in 2009 and 2001 respectively. The retail market level has moved from low concentration in 2009 to highly moderately concentrated quartile. The HHI index of the ex-farm market was above 1800 quartile for the three years of reference, while the wholesale remain in the low concentration throughout the study years the retail industry has roused from HHI 205, 980 and 1395 in 2009, 2010 and 2011 respectively. The performance indictors revealed there has been positive but low return on assets for both market levels in the year of reference, the ROE and ROS are also positive but slightly better with the values increasing over the last three years of reference. The study examines the vertical price relationship to evaluate degree of market power and competition along the market supply chain. Monthly average for the whole Malaysia price data 2004M01 to 2010M12 of standard broiler chicken for farm gate, wholesale and retail were analyze using co-integration technique. The results of the unit root test for both ADF and PP rejected the null hypothesis of unit root at 5% significance after first difference of the series indicating that the variables are integrated of same order I(1). All the lag selection criteria LR, FPE, AIC, SC and HQ suggest optimum lag of 1. The Johansen-Juselius co-integration test results show both Trace test and Max-Eigen test are statically significant to reject the null hypothesis of no co-integration among the variables (r= 0) at 5% significance level. The VECM result indicates the causality of variables in the system, and the direction of causality within the sample period. The coefficient of the lag dependant variable and the error correction term in equation (2) are both significant indicating a bi-directional between retail price and farm price. There is unidirectional causality from farm to wholesale but at 10% significance level. The result is consistent with earlier studies, but conclusion could not be made at this point because the causality does not provide us with the dynamic interactions. The dynamic interaction analysis among variables was conducted through variance decomposition (VDC) and impulse response functions (IRF). -1. 8044 -2. 9993 -1. 6375 -2. 9827 -4. 8053** -4. 9420** -4. 4690** -4. 5591** -2. 2393 -3. 4034* -2. 0055 -3. 3979* -7. 3721** -7. 3664** -9. 8519** -9. 9062** -7. 0077** -6. 9595** -28. 7019** -28. 3716** -7. 6739** -7. 6920** -9. 8427** -9. 9220** ** and * denotes significant at 5% and 10% significance level. 0 297. 4498 NA 3. 39E-09 -8. 151384 -8. 024903 -8. 101032 1 488. 4225 355. 4213* 2. 63E-11* -13. 01174* -12. 37933* -12. 75997* 2 502. 5870 24. 78779 2. 78E-11 -12. 96075 -11. 82242 -12. 50757 3 509. 7813 11. 79078 3. 59E-11 -12. 71615 -11. 07189 -12. 06156 4 522. 0813 18. 79162 4. 05E-11 -12. 61337 -10. 46319 -11. 75737 *indicates lowest lag order of the criteria. FPE= Final predictor error, AIC= Akaike information criteria SC= Schwarz information criteria, HQ= Hannan-Quinin information criteria r= 0 70. 4759** 31. 8713** 47. 85613 27. 58434 r≤1 38. 6042 31. 0465 29. 79707 21. 13162 r≤2 7. 5581 5. 4143 15. 49471 14. 2646 r≤3 2. 1439 2. 1439 3. 841466 3. 841466 Note: ** donates Significant at 5% levels. ΔRP ΔFP ΔWP ΔRP 9. 031** [0. 002] 1. 833 [0. 176] 0. 197** (3. 353) ΔFP 0. 039 [0. 844] 0. 242 [0. 623] 1. 284 (5. 522) ΔWP 0. 075 [0. 784] 2. 890* [0. 090] 0. 263* (3. 060) * and ** denotes significance at 10% and 5% significance level, respectively. The figures in the parenthesis denote as t-statistics and figures in the squared brackets represents as p-value. RP= log retail price, FP= log farm level price, WP= log wholesale price and Δ denotes change. Market conduct Indicators
Market Performance Indicators
Price Asymmetry Model
Results and Discussion
S-C-P Results
Asymmerty Results
Table 1: Unit Root Testing Results
Augmented Dickey Fuller
(ADF)
Phillips-Perror
(PP)
Level
Variable
Constant Without Trend
Constant With Trend
Constant Without Trend
Constant With Trend
Retail
Farm
Wholesale
First difference
Retail
Farm
Wholesale
Table 2: Results of Optimum Lag Order Selection Criteria
Lag
LagL
LR
FPE
AIC
SC
HQ
Table 3: Co-integration tests results
Hypothesized
No. of CE'(s)
Trace
Max-Eigen
Critical Values (5%)
Statistic
Statistic
Trace
Max-Eigen
Table 4: Causality and price transmission results
Dependant Variables
Independent Variables
Long-run causality
Short-run Causality
–
–
–